My WebLink
|
Help
|
About
|
Sign Out
Home
Browse
Search
SR0084717_SSNL
Environmental Health - Public
>
EHD Program Facility Records by Street Name
>
A
>
AUSTIN
>
285
>
2600 - Land Use Program
>
SR0084717_SSNL
Metadata
Thumbnails
Annotations
Entry Properties
Last modified
2/17/2022 12:18:44 PM
Creation date
1/13/2022 9:53:59 AM
Metadata
Fields
Template:
EHD - Public
ProgramCode
2600 - Land Use Program
FileName_PostFix
SSNL
RECORD_ID
SR0084717
PE
2602
FACILITY_NAME
285 S AUSTIN RD
STREET_NUMBER
285
Direction
S
STREET_NAME
AUSTIN
STREET_TYPE
RD
City
MANTECA
Zip
95336
APN
22802048
ENTERED_DATE
1/12/2022 12:00:00 AM
SITE_LOCATION
285 S AUSTIN RD
P_LOCATION
04
P_DISTRICT
003
QC Status
Approved
Scanner
SJGOV\tsok
Tags
EHD - Public
Jump to thumbnail
< previous set
next set >
There are no annotations on this page.
Document management portal powered by Laserfiche WebLink 9 © 1998-2015
Laserfiche.
All rights reserved.
/
1028
PDF
Print
Pages to print
Enter page numbers and/or page ranges separated by commas. For example, 1,3,5-12.
After downloading, print the document using a PDF reader (e.g. Adobe Reader).
View images
View plain text
98 Part i california Water <br />of how much people would be willing to pay not to have their supplies reduced.22 <br />This willingness to pay increases as water becomes scarcer, and it is likely higher <br />in the short term than in the longer term—when time allows adaptation with <br />new technology, such as more efficient shower heads or low-water-using plants.23 <br />As shown in Chapter 6, continued urban conservation will be important <br />for managing scarce water resources, and this shift will be most effective if <br />technologies, tastes, and habits can adapt to minimize the costs of adjustment. <br />An especially important frontier will be outdoor water use, which now accounts <br />for most net urban use (residential exterior, large landscape, plus some propor- <br />tion of commercial and industrial uses—Figure 2.12). Shifting landscapes from <br />thirsty lawns to low-water-using plants can greatly reduce net urban water use <br />(Hanak and Davis 2006). <br />Do urban water users pay too little? <br />In water management circles, it is often said that California’s urban water users <br />pay too little for water. A comparison is made with monthly cell phone bills, <br />and the implication is that consumers are getting a bargain on their water <br />bill relative to the value of the water to them—or the amount they would (or <br />should) be willing to pay. The comparison with cell phone bills is apt. As of 2006, <br />the average price of treated water delivered to households was roughly $960 <br />per acre-foot (in 2008 $), and the average monthly water bill for single-family <br />households was $42, less than a typical cell phone subscription (Table 2.4). <br />The important question, however, is not whether users pay too little rela- <br />tive to the value of water to them—this is true, on average, for most goods and <br />services.24 Rather, what matters from a water policy perspective is whether they <br />pay enough to cover the full costs of providing water, including the capital and <br />maintenance costs to the water utility and the costs of protecting environmental <br />values affected by water diversions. As discussed below in our review of water system <br />finances, the first part of this answer is a qualified “yes,” but the second part is a defi- <br />nite “no.” Not only can adapting water prices to reflect the full cost of water generate <br />an appropriate stream of funding for public benefits of the water system, it can also <br />send the right signal to consumers to use the resource more efficiently (Chapter 6). <br />22. See Renwick and Green (2000), Barakat & Chamberlin, Inc. (1994), Genius et al. (2008), Jenkins, Lund, and Howitt <br />(2003), Rosenberg, Howitt, and Lund (2008), Rosenberg et al. (2008), and California Department of Water Resources (2009). <br />23. Economists also measure the consumer benefits from using water under different water price structures by comparing <br />the additional benefits from additional amounts of water consumed to the marginal cost (price) of that amount (Hewitt <br />and Hanemann 1995; Olmsted, Hanemann, and Stavins 2007; Hall 1996). As discussed in Chapter 6, the social goal is to <br />design an economically efficient, revenue sufficient, and politically acceptable water rate (Hall 2000, 2009). <br />24. Economists refer to the excess in willingness to pay over price as the “consumer surplus.”
The URL can be used to link to this page
Your browser does not support the video tag.