Laserfiche WebLink
98 Part i california Water <br />of how much people would be willing to pay not to have their supplies reduced.22 <br />This willingness to pay increases as water becomes scarcer, and it is likely higher <br />in the short term than in the longer term—when time allows adaptation with <br />new technology, such as more efficient shower heads or low-water-using plants.23 <br />As shown in Chapter 6, continued urban conservation will be important <br />for managing scarce water resources, and this shift will be most effective if <br />technologies, tastes, and habits can adapt to minimize the costs of adjustment. <br />An especially important frontier will be outdoor water use, which now accounts <br />for most net urban use (residential exterior, large landscape, plus some propor- <br />tion of commercial and industrial uses—Figure 2.12). Shifting landscapes from <br />thirsty lawns to low-water-using plants can greatly reduce net urban water use <br />(Hanak and Davis 2006). <br />Do urban water users pay too little? <br />In water management circles, it is often said that California’s urban water users <br />pay too little for water. A comparison is made with monthly cell phone bills, <br />and the implication is that consumers are getting a bargain on their water <br />bill relative to the value of the water to them—or the amount they would (or <br />should) be willing to pay. The comparison with cell phone bills is apt. As of 2006, <br />the average price of treated water delivered to households was roughly $960 <br />per acre-foot (in 2008 $), and the average monthly water bill for single-family <br />households was $42, less than a typical cell phone subscription (Table 2.4). <br />The important question, however, is not whether users pay too little rela- <br />tive to the value of water to them—this is true, on average, for most goods and <br />services.24 Rather, what matters from a water policy perspective is whether they <br />pay enough to cover the full costs of providing water, including the capital and <br />maintenance costs to the water utility and the costs of protecting environmental <br />values affected by water diversions. As discussed below in our review of water system <br />finances, the first part of this answer is a qualified “yes,” but the second part is a defi- <br />nite “no.” Not only can adapting water prices to reflect the full cost of water generate <br />an appropriate stream of funding for public benefits of the water system, it can also <br />send the right signal to consumers to use the resource more efficiently (Chapter 6). <br />22. See Renwick and Green (2000), Barakat & Chamberlin, Inc. (1994), Genius et al. (2008), Jenkins, Lund, and Howitt <br />(2003), Rosenberg, Howitt, and Lund (2008), Rosenberg et al. (2008), and California Department of Water Resources (2009). <br />23. Economists also measure the consumer benefits from using water under different water price structures by comparing <br />the additional benefits from additional amounts of water consumed to the marginal cost (price) of that amount (Hewitt <br />and Hanemann 1995; Olmsted, Hanemann, and Stavins 2007; Hall 1996). As discussed in Chapter 6, the social goal is to <br />design an economically efficient, revenue sufficient, and politically acceptable water rate (Hall 2000, 2009). <br />24. Economists refer to the excess in willingness to pay over price as the “consumer surplus.”